Managing economic and social profit of cooperative models in three-echelon reverse supply chain for waste electrical and electronic equipment
Jian Li, Zhen Wang, Bao Jiang
Managing economic and social profit of cooperative models in three-echelon reverse supply chain for waste electrical and electronic equipment
The four model of a three-echelon reverse supply chain (RSC) for WEEE are studied.
Optimal coordination strategies in four models are compared.
The model C make the RSC of WEEE achieve maximum economic and social benefit.
Duopolistic retailers make the RSC achieve maximum economic and social benefit.
In addition to maximizing economic benefits, reverse supply chains should further seek to maximize social benefits by increasing the quantity of waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE). The paper investigates cooperative models with different parties in a three-echelon reverse supply chain for WEEE consisting of a single collector, a single remanufacturer, and two retailers based on complete information. In addition, the optimal decisions of four cooperative models and the effect of the market demand of remanufactured WEEE products and the market share of two retailers on the optimal decisions are discussed. The results indicate that optimal total channel profit and recycle quantity in a reverse supply chain are maximized in a centralized model. The optimal total channel profit and recycle quantity increase with an increase in the market demand of remanufactured WEEE products. The three-echelon reverse supply chain consisting of duopolistic retailers maximizes total channel profit and recycle quantity in a reverse supply chain for WEEE.
Waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) / Reverse supply chains / Recycle quantity / Social benefit / Cooperative models / Duopolistic retailers
[1] |
Neto J Q F, Walther G, Bloemhof J, van Nunen J, Spengler T. From closed-loop to sustainable supply chains: The WEEE case. International Journal of Production Research, 2010, 48(15): 4463–4481
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[2] |
Robinson B H. E-waste: An assessment of global production and environmental impacts. Science of the Total Environment, 2009, 408(2): 183–191
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[3] |
Ongondo F O, Williams I D, Cherrett T J. How are WEEE doing? A global review of the management of electrical and electronic wastes. Waste Management (New York, N.Y.), 2011, 31(4): 714–730
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[4] |
He W Z, Li G M, Ma X F, Wang H, Huang J W, Xu M, Huang C. WEEE recovery strategies and the WEEE treatment status in China. Journal of Hazardous Materials, 2006, 136(3): 502–512
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[5] |
Sepulveda A, Schluep M, Renaud F G, Streicher M, Kuehr R, Hageluken C, Gerecke A C. A review of the environmental fate and effects of hazardous substances released from electrical and electronic equipments during recycling: Examples from China and India. Environmental Impact Assessment Review, 2010, 30(1): 28–41
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[6] |
Tsydenova O, Bengtsson M. Chemical hazards associated with treatment of waste electrical and electronic equipment. Waste Management (New York, N.Y.), 2011, 31(1): 45–58
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[7] |
Alzate A, Lopez M E, Serna C. Recovery of gold from waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) using ammonium persulfate. Waste Management (New York, N.Y.), 2016, 57: 113–120
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[8] |
Cui J, Forssberg E. Mechanical recycling of waste electric and electronic equipment: A review. Journal of Hazardous Materials, 2003, 99(3): 243–263
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[9] |
Cui J, Forssberg E. Characterization of shredded television scrap and implications for materials recovery. Waste Management (New York, N.Y.), 2007, 27(3): 415–424
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[10] |
Dowlatshahi S. Developing a theory of reverse logistics. Interfaces, 2000, 30(3): 143–155
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[11] |
Liu X B, Tanaka M, Matsui Y. Economic evaluation of optional recycling processes for waste electronic home appliances. Journal of Cleaner Production, 2009, 17(1): 53–60
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[12] |
Chi X W, Streicher-Porte M, Wang M Y L, Reuter M A. Informal electronic waste recycling: A sector review with special focus on China. Waste Management (New York, N.Y.), 2011, 31(4): 731–742
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[13] |
Debo L G, Toktay L B, Van Wassenhove L N. Market segmentation and product technology selection for remanufacturable products. Management Science, 2005, 51(8): 1193–1205
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[14] |
Sabbaghi M, Behdad S, Zhuang J. Managing consumer behavior toward on-time return of the waste electrical and electronic equipment: A game theoretic approach. International Journal of Production Economics, 2016, 182: 545–563
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[15] |
Savaskan R C, Van Wassenhove L N. Reverse channel design: The case of competing retailers. Management Science, 2006, 52(1): 1–14
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[16] |
Webster S, Mitra S. Competitive strategy in remanufacturing and the impact of take-back laws. Journal of Operations Management, 2007, 25(6): 1123–1140
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[17] |
Toyasaki F, Boyaci T, Verter V. An analysis of monopolistic and competitive take-back schemes for WEEE recycling. Production and Operations Management, 2011, 20(6): 805–823
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[18] |
Hong I H, Ke J S. Determining advanced recycling fees and subsidies in “E-scrap” reverse supply chains. Journal of Environmental Management, 2011, 92(6): 1495–1502
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[19] |
Jacobs B W, Subramanian R. Sharing responsibility for product recovery across the supply chain. Production and Operations Management, 2012, 21(1): 85–100
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[20] |
Guo Y H, Ma J H. Research on game model and complexity of retailer collecting and selling in closed-loop supply chain. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 2013, 37(7): 5047–5058
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[21] |
Stevels A, Huisman J, Wang F, Li J H, Li B Y, Duan H B. Take back and treatment of discarded electronics: A scientific update. Frontiers of Environmental Science & Engineering, 2013, 7(4): 475–482
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[22] |
Pangburn M S, Stavrulaki E. Take back costs and product durability. European Journal of Operational Research, 2014, 238(1): 175–184
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[23] |
Zhang P, Xiong Y, Xiong Z K, Yan W. Designing contracts for a closed-loop supply chain under information asymmetry. Operations Research Letters, 2014, 42(2): 150–155
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[24] |
De Giovanni P, Reddy P V, Zaccour G. Incentive strategies for an optimal recovery program in a closed-loop supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 2016, 249(2): 605–617
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[25] |
Xiao T J, Shi K R, Yang D Q. Coordination of a supply chain with consumer return under demand uncertainty. International Journal of Production Economics, 2010, 124(1): 171–180
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[26] |
Wei J, Zhao J. Pricing decisions with retail competition in a fuzzy closed-loop supply chain. Expert Systems with Applications, 2011, 38(9): 11209–11216
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[27] |
Shi Z Y, Wang N M, Jia T, Chen H X. Reverse revenue sharing contract versus two-part tariff contract under a closed-loop supply chain system. Mathematical Problems in Engineering, 2016, 2016(2): 1–15
|
[28] |
Ma Z J, Zhang N A, Dai Y, Hu S. Managing channel profits of different cooperative models in closed-loop supply chains. Omega, 2016, 59: 251–262
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[29] |
Weng T C, Chen C K. Competitive Analysis of collection behavior between retailer and third-party in the reverse channel. Operations Research, 2016, 50(1): 175–188
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[30] |
Li J, Wang Z, Jiang B, Kim T. Coordination strategies in a three-echelon reverse supply chain for economic and social benefit. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 2017, 49: 599–611
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
[31] |
Modak N M, Panda S, Sana S S. Three-echelon supply chain coordination considering duopolistic retailers with perfect quality products. International Journal of Production Economics, 2016, 182: 564–578
CrossRef
Google scholar
|
/
〈 | 〉 |